Saturday, October 27, 2012

The Market Demand for Private Goods and Public Goods



      In economics, a public good is a good that is both non-excludable and non-rivalrous in that individuals cannot be effectively excluded from use and where use by one individual does not reduce availability to others. Some examples of public goods include fresh air, knowledge, lighthouse, national defence, flood control systems and street lighting. Public goods that are available everywhere are sometimes referred as global public goods. As such the overall value of public goods is obtained by summing the value that each individual receives for a given quantity. The non-rivalrous nature of public goods consumption makes the derivation of the market demand different from that of private goods. The difference is horizontal versus vertical. Many public goods may at times be subject to excessive use affecting all users such as air pollution and traffic congestion. Public goods are often closely related to the ‘free-rider’ which meant people not paying for the good may continue to access it. Besides that, the goods may be under-produced, overused or degraded.

         In economics, private good is defined as “an item that yields positive benefits to people” that is excludable which meant its owner can exercise private property rights, preventing those who have not paid for it from using the good or consuming its benefits. Besides that, rivalrous meant consumption by one necessarily prevents that of another. A private good is scarce in economic resource and can cause competition for it. The market demand curve for a private good is a horizontal summation of individual demand curves. Private goods are less likely to have the free rider problem compare to the public goods. Assuming a private good is valued positively by everyone, the efficiency of obtaining the good is obstructed by its rivalry which is simultaneous consumption of a rivalrous good is theoretically impossible. Besides that, the feasibility of obtaining the good is made difficult by its excludability meant that people have to pay for it to enjoy its benefits.
       As mentioned earlier, the market demand for private goods is derived through the horizontal summation of individual demand curves. Furthermore, the market demand for public goods is derived through the vertical summation of individual demand curves. For private goods, the market demand will answer the question “What is the total quantity that buyers would be willing to purchase at given price?” while for public goods, the market demand will answer this question “what is the total value or benefit generated from consuming a given quantity?”

                                       Private Goods Demand

The Market Demand for Private Goods
     To see the difference between private and public goods, first consider the market demand for private goods. The primary focus of the market demand for private goods is on the price that the buyers pay. The total market demand is derived by adding up or summing the quantity demanded by every buyer at a given price. For example, the market demand for stuffed animals. This particular market contains only two buyers, Muizz and Azim. Suppose that Muizz is willing and able to purchase 2 stuffed animals at a $1 price and Azim is willing and able to purchase 6 stuffed animals at this price. In this case, the total market demand at the $1 price is 8 stuffed animals which is 2 + 6. The market demand curve is then derived by identifying the quantities that these two buyers would be willing and able to purchase at different prices.
      The market demand is the horizontal summation of the individual demand curves of Muizz and Azim. The quantities are horizontally summed for a given price. The resulting red demand curve is the market demand for stuffed animal.
                                                     Public Good Demand

The Market Demand for Public Goods
      Non-rivalrous consumption makes the derivation of the demand for public goods a different story. Everyone can enjoy the benefits of a public good simultaneously. The consumption by one person does not prevent the consumption by another. As such, the value society receives from a public good is the sum of the value received by all who enjoy the benefits. This means that the demand for public goods is based on the vertical summation of individual demand curves.
      For example let's return to our two buyers, Muizz and Azim. However, in this case they are consuming a public good, such as national defence. The focus of attention is now on the price each buyer would be willing to pay for a given quantity of the good let’s say 2 fighter jets. Suppose that Muizz is willing and able to pay $1 for a given level of defence and Azim is willing and able to pay $3 for this level. The total market demand is the sum of the prices that each is willing to pay, which is $4 ($1 + $3). The market demand curve is then derived by summing the prices that these two buyers would be willing and able to pay for different quantities. The market demand curve is the vertical summation of the individual demand curves of Muizz and Azim. The prices are vertically summed for a given quantity. This new red demand curve labeled D is now the market demand for the public good.

        The conclusion of these private and public goods is that the difference is subtle, but key to an understanding of public goods. Efficiency dictates that the extra benefit generated by a good is equal to the extra opportunity cost of production which meant the marginal benefit generated from the production of one more unit of the good is equal to the marginal cost of production. Furthermore, because private goods are rivalrous in consumption, the production of one more unit of the good can be consumed only by one person. Efficiency is then achieved when the extra benefit received by that one person is equal to the extra cost of production.

        In other hand, the story is a different for public goods that are non-rivalrous in consumption. This is because public goods are consumed by everyone simultaneously and the extra benefit derived from consumption is the extra benefit by everyone combined. This can be obtained by summing the extra benefit that each receives, which meant by summing the price each is willing to pay.

Posted by Muhammad Faizzullah

1 comment: